Into The Valley Of Death

Originally published in the Informanté newspaper on Thursday, 4 February, 2016.


In 1958, economist William Phillips, a New Zealander, published a paper titled ‘The Relation between Unemployment and the Rate of Change of Money Wage Rates in the United Kingdom.’ It was an unwieldy title for a rather simple relationship that he discovered in the economy of the United Kingdom, and with some more research by Paul Samuelson and Robert Solow, his discovery eventually became known as the Phillips curve.

What Phillips discovered in his data, it seemed, was an inverse relationship between inflation and unemployment – higher inflation resulted in lower unemployment, and vice versa. But while the data did indeed show this, any student of African economies would by now be able to point out that this vastly simplifies this relationship, and common sense nowadays shows this is not true. 


It was not even a decade before this ‘Phillips curve myth’ was exposed for what it was. During the 1970’s inflation skyrocketed in developed nations and unemployment soared, in direct contradiction to what the Phillips curve predicted. Developed economies entered into a recession, and economic theories that depended on the Phillips curve could not offer a solution. But does this not sound eerily familiar?

In South Africa, growth forecasts have been cut time and time again. The latest by the IMF predicts just a 0.7% growth for the former regional powerhouse. With strikes increasing in frequency and with electricity supply issues, industrial development is stalling, and alongside it, employment opportunities. Coupled with the deteriorating Rand, the South African economy is again starting to experience strong inflationary pressures, which resulted in the South African Reserve Bank recently increasing its repo rate to attempt to head it off.

Luckily, we’re no longer dependent on the ‘Phillips Curve’ economists. Unfortunately, that does not make us as much wiser as we would have hoped. 

Inflation, for instance, generally refers to the increase in the price of goods. But seen economically, it can also be seen as a reduction in the purchasing power of currency. There is only X amount of goods that can be bought with Y amount of money. If the amount of money increases, but the amount of goods remains the same, you’ll need more money to buy the same amount of goods.

To control inflation, then, the Reserve Bank needs to reduce the amount of money – and so, it increases the cost of borrowing money. By increasing interest rates, money that would instead be used to buy goods and services, is now used to service debt. Money is taken out of circulation, and inflation is kept under control.

But economic growth is measured by the amount of goods and services produced and consumed… So with more money being used to service debt, and less applied to buying goods and services, economic growth slows – which is not what we want! Especially not in a potential recession! 

The solution to this, naturally, is to substitute private spending with government spending. Or it would be, were it not for the fact that government spending is usually funded by issuing debt. And with the international ratings agencies already concerned with South Africa’s ability to repay its debt, with a potential ratings downgrade to junk already on the cards, it is just not possible. 

It seems South Africa is suffering from the failure of a different kind of Phillips Curve. Constrained by previous government policies is such a way that a fiscal stimulus is impossible, South Africa seems trapped into either allowing growth and rampant inflation (which will swallow that growth whole) or containing inflation at the cost of stagnation. 

It thus becomes tempting to look back at those developed economies and try and apply their solution to the stagflation problem here. Unfortunately, while the inviolability of the Phillip Curve was dealt a critical blow by stagflation, Phillips did correctly identify a relationship between unemployment and inflation, albeit only in the short-term.

In the United States, for example, Paul Volcker aggressively targeted inflation by raising interest rates, which successfully curbed inflation at the cost of high unemployment rates and a temporarily worsened recession.  While this certainly remain an option for the South African Reserve Bank, in the current South African political climate an increase in unemployment would only serve to exacerbate tensions with the government, and might cost the country what little political stability it has left.

There might be a different course to recovery though. In certain cases, growth stagnation can be caused by excessive regulation of labour and goods markets. It seems reasonable to assume that relaxing a regulatory regime could do the opposite. With government fiscal stimulus out of the question, perhaps a private stimulus is needed. Suppose the government of South Africa instead aggressively cuts the red tape that is strangling its culture of entrepreneurship, and allows it to blossom. Perhaps South Africa can kick-start an ‘entrepreneurial’ stimulus to counteract its recessionary malaise, and lead the BRICS nations into a new golden age. Then perhaps it can crawl through the jaws of death, back from the mouth of hell…

No comments:

Post a Comment